It
is perhaps surprising that so much attention has been given to the
Single Market, yet so little attention has been paid to the EU
Customs Union. Particularly as leaving the EU Customs Union has
potentially greater impacts on UK trade than leaving the Single
Market :
-
A repatriated trade policy will need new WTO Schedules and new 3rd country trade agreements.
-
Trade with the EU will face imposition of tariffs or Rules of Origin processing and a new customs border.
In
my previous
post, I looked at the impact of leaving the Customs Union and a
repatriated trade policy.
In
this post, I will look at the impact of Tariffs / Rules of Origin
processing on UK-EU trade.
Tariffs
If
the UK leaves the EU's Customs Union and Single Market without
sealing a Free Trade Agreement (FTA), then tariffs will apply to
future UK-EU trade.
Staying
in the Single Market via the EFTA EEA option would allow tariff-free
trade to continue, but not for all goods. Article 8.3 of the EEA
agreement states the agreement applies to “products falling
within Chapters 25 to 97 of the Harmonized Commodity Description and
Coding System”, i.e. manufactured goods only. Chapters 1-24 of
the Harmonised
Commodity Description and Coding System covers agriculture &
fisheries products:
-
Section I. Chapters 1-5: LIVE ANIMALS; ANIMAL PRODUCTS
-
Section II. Chapters 6-14: VEGETABLE PRODUCTS
-
Section III. Chapter 15: ANIMAL OR VEGETABLE FATS AND OILS AND THEIR CLEAVAGE PRODUCTS; PREPARED EDIBLE FATS; ANIMAL OR VEGETABLE WAXES
-
Section IV. Chapters 16-24: PREPARED FOODSTUFFS; BEVERAGES, SPIRITS AND VINEGAR; TOBACCO AND MANUFACTURED TOBACCO SUBSTITUTES
Agriculture
& fisheries products excluded from the EEA agreement typically
attract the highest tariffs. A Civitas study “Potential
post-Brexit tariff costs for EU-UK trade” identifies the 10 UK
export sectors impacted by high tariff rates (%) (table 3:10) –
all 10 are agriculture & fisheries sectors not covered by the EEA
agreement – with tariffs of 40% in some cases. High tariffs on
agriculture & fisheries would obviously create an initial shock
for UK producers and consumers, as indeed there was when the UK
joined the EEC in 1973 and lost preferential access to Commonwealth
agriculture markets.
Tariffs
for manufactured goods are typically much lower than for agriculture
& fisheries products, although some manufactured goods would face
tariffs above 5%: most textiles, some chemicals, plastics, ceramics
and aluminium and most notably a 10% tariff on finished cars. The
Civitas study “Potential
post-Brexit tariff costs for EU-UK trade” also identifies the
top 10 UK exports sectors impacted by value of duty payable (£)
(table 2:10), and the car sector is top at £1.3bn (4 of the top 10
are again agriculture & fisheries sectors).
Not
that reverting to tariffs for UK-EU trade is all bad news:
-
As identified in a report by the Agriculture & Horticulture Development Board, the UK currently trades at a significant deficit with the EU in many agricultural products, which provides opportunities for import substitution.
- An expected consequence of the UK and EU failing to agree an FTA would be a lower £, reducing the impact of tariffs on UK exports, while at the same exacerbating the impacts of tariffs on EU exports to the UK. This will also impact UK manufacturers who use imported components – which may in turn provide an incentive to source UK alternatives.
-
Based on current trade, UK exports to the EU would incur duty of £5.2 billion, EU exports to the UK would incur duty of £12.9 billion paid into the UK Treasury - a handy windfall. Although in practice trade diversion and duty relief schemes will reduce these figures.
-
Duty can be reduced or eliminated where imports are consumed in the production of an exported product.
To
alleviate the impact of EU tariffs, the UK Government could re-cycle
revenue from UK import duty. A cut in corporation tax has been
suggested, but this would not target the small number of companies
who export to the EU. WTO rules prohibit payment of subsidies direct
to exporters, but as described in a Civitas
paper on mitigating the effect of UK-EU tariffs, the UK could implement a number of WTO-compliant schemes (provided the UK is outside the EU Single Market restrictive state aid
rules) :
-
Implement greater tax incentives for research and development expenditure for all businesses. The cost would be in the region of £2.9 billion, of which £2.1 billion (73%) would go to industries suffering EU-27 tariffs.
-
Operate a more extensive regional aid programme. Using simple rules acceptable to the WTO, areas covering 65% of the population could receive assistance worth £3.8 billion, of which £3.1 billion (82%) would go to exporting industries. At present EU rules limit the UK to assisting areas covering only 27% of the population.
-
Redesign its energy policy. Whatever it decides to do about emissions trading, and wider climate change policy, abolition of the damaging carbon price floor mechanism makes sense in its own right. It would release £1.2 billion in costs, including £392 million for domestic users of electricity.
-
Transitional Assistance Programme (TAP), a discretionary economy-wide scheme making payments to aid adjustment costs arising from Brexit, capped in practice at 1% of the value of a business’ exports. Set at that level, the scheme would not infringe WTO rules on actionable subsidies.
Import
tariffs will also impact UK manufacturers and exporters who use
components sourced from the EU. In particular, the
car industry uses complex supply chains involving multiple channel
crossings; UK manufactured cars typically have a high proportion
of EU components. However, the WTO
Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures allows for
“remission or drawback” schemes (i.e. refund of duty already
paid) on imports that are consumed in the production of an exported
product. As discussed in the Legatum
Institute paper on Brexit and supply chains (chapter 5), the EU's
Union Customs Code (UCC), which is to be adopted into UK law as part
of the Great Repeal Bill, provides a number of such schemes to
provide relief from import duties, e.g.:
-
Inward Processing. Import of materials which are then re-exported.
-
Outward Processing. Import of goods produced from goods previously exported.
-
End Use Relief Import of goods for specific end uses, such as qualifying aircraft parts.
-
Storage via Customs Warehousing or Free Zones
Rules
of Origin (RoO)
A
UK-EU FTA would provide preferential tariff or tariff-free trade, but
outside the EU's Customs Union, UK exporters to the EU will face a
Rules of Origin (RoO) hurdle. This hurdle applies to all third
countries outside the EU's Customs Union, including the EFTA EEA
states (Norway, Iceland & Liechtenstein). Staying in the Single
Market via the EFTA EEA option does not avoid the RoO hurdle.
Rules
of Origin (RoO) are criteria to determine where a product
originates from, which determines whether the product qualifies for
preferential tariff under an FTA. Products must either be (i)
manufactured from raw materials or components which have been grown
or produced in the exporters home country, or (ii) have undergone
sufficient processing in the exporters home country. This avoids
products from third countries who do not have an FTA gaining
preferential access “by the back door”.
EEA
Rules of Origin are defined in
EEA
agreement Protocol 4.
As
described in the EEA
Factsheet on Trade in Goods,
EFTA EEA states are part of the Pan
Euro-Mediterranean (PEM) Free Trade system
-
a
network of Free
Trade Agreements (FTAs)
with
identical
RoO
protocols.
PEM
participants
are:
the
EU, All EFTA States (including
non-EEA Switzerland), Turkey, signatories
to the
Barcelona Declaration (Morocco,
Algeria, Tunisia, Egypt, Jordan, the Palestinian Authority, Syria,
Lebanon, Turkey and Israel)
the Western Balkans and the Faroe Islands. All
these individual
origin
protocols are
being replaced by a reference to
the
Pan
Euro-Mediterranean (PEM) Convention,
a
single convention to
facilitate
on-going revision to
modernise and simplify PEM
rules of origin.
A
key
aspect of RoO
is “cumulation”. This allows goods
incorporating products
from 3rd
countries to still qualify as an originating product and
a
preferential tariff. There are 3 types of cumulation:
-
Bi-lateral Cumulation. Input originating (i.e. as per the RoO criteria) in one party to a Free Trade Agreement qualifies as originating input in the other party (e.g. if product imported from first party is incorporated into a product by the second party which is then exported to first party).
-
Diagonal Cumulation. Same as bilateral cumulation, but operates between more than two countries provided they have all concluded Free Trade Agreements between themselves. This promotes longer supply chains, although the full RoO qualifying criteria must be met at each point in the chain
- Full Cumulation. All stages of processing or transformation of a product within a full cumulation zone count towards RoO qualification. Whereas bi-lateral or diagonal cumulation requires RoO criteria to be met in each country in the chain, full cumulation allows the RoO critera to be distributed across any number of countries within the full cumulation zone – allowing for greater fragmentation of the production process and more complex supply chains.
Within
the PEM zone, Full cumulation applies between the EU, EEA, Algeria,
Morocco and Tunisia. The remaining PEM countries apply Bi-lateral /
Diagonal cumulation only (see EU
web page on Cumulation arrangements). Ideally, the UK would
remain in the PEM zone with Full cumulation as at present to avoid
damaging existing supply chains (including cases where EU/EEA
products imported to UK have a production process distributed across
EU/EEA). UK exporters to the EU would use the
EUR1
form
- the
EUR1
form is already in use today for UK exports to non-EU PEM states.
Similarly,
EU exporters would use the EUR1 form for trade with the
UK.
UK
exporters to the EU will face a one-off cost to modify their supply
chain management processes to produce RoO paperwork (although
companies
who export to countries with which the EU has preferential trade
agreements will already be handling RoO).
There
will also be on-going RoO administration costs, for which there are a
wide-range of estimates:
-
The Treasury report produced during the Referendum campaign estimated approximately 50% of UK exports to EU could be impacted (see para 2.62). The same report also quotes a variety of sources for on-going costs of RoO (Box A.1) – with estimates ranging from 3% to 15% of transaction values.
-
A more optimistic estimate was provided well before the Referendum campaign by an HM Government FOI response on EU membership and the costs of new customs controls (including RoO): “UK goods would be subject to customs controls (and would have to conform to product specifications outside our control) – a burden on business in addition to current EU regulations estimated at 2% of transaction values”
- Open Europe's 2014 Brexit Report assumed a RoO cost as 4% of transaction values as input to a dynamic economic model. The model suggested a 1-1.2% GDP loss from leaving the Customs Union, largely arising from RoO costs. A more recent Open Europe article on the Customs Union repeated the 1-1.2% GDP loss and described the figure as “clearly not prohibitively high”.
It
should also be borne in mind that a great number of
manufactured goods
will fall into the category of “middle
products” (tariff =
1%-5%)
or “de
minimis products” (tariff
below 1%).
For these products, the
cost of RoO is close to or exceeds the savings via
preferential trade,
so in many cases the importer will simply follow the non-preferential
route, avoid the RoO
hurdle and pay the full
tariff.
Whatever
the cost of RoO, it is dead-weight cost for the economy incurred by
leaving the EU Customs Union to regain control of our trade policy
and freedom to negotiate our own FTA's. As UK trade becomes
more global (UK exports to the Rest of the World overtook exports to
the EU some years ago, even as members of the EU), RoO will in any
case increasingly become a fact of life for exporters.
Conclusion
Leaving
the Customs Union, but staying in the Single Market via EFTA EEA
option makes little sense from the point of view of tariffs:
-
Tariffs on manufacturing goods are avoided (typically less than 10%), but the highest tariffs are on agriculture & fisheries products, which are not covered by the EEA agreement.
-
RoO hurdle and cost is encountered, which negates savings on tariffs for “middle products” and “de minimis products” (i.e. tariffs less than 5%)
-
The UK is still subject to Single Market rules, including state aid rules that are much more restrictive than WTO rules.
While
tariff-free trade should always be sought, the imposition of tariffs
on UK-EU trade would not be disastrous:
-
There will be opportunities for import substitution (especially in agriculture & fisheries).
-
The impact on supply chains can be mitigated via duty drawback and relief.
-
There is no RoO hurdle or cost.
-
Import duty windfall can be re-cycled to UK exporters via WTO-compliant schemes (provided UK is free from EU state aid rules).
This
emphasises the point made by many commentators
that
non-tariff barriers are more important than tariffs. In
my next post, I will look at the potential non-tariff barriers
arising from a new customs border with the EU.
UPDATE 3/12/2017: It should also be noted that Rules of Origin also applies to goods imported via a non-preferential route. The primary purpose of this is is to identify goods that breach the EU's anti-dumping measures (e.g. use of Chinese Steel) and other trade defence measures. While the UK's anti-dumping measures & trade defence measures continue to mirror the EU's, non-preferential RoO *ought* not to be an issue - but that assumes the EU take a pragmatic view.
UPDATE 3/12/2017: It should also be noted that Rules of Origin also applies to goods imported via a non-preferential route. The primary purpose of this is is to identify goods that breach the EU's anti-dumping measures (e.g. use of Chinese Steel) and other trade defence measures. While the UK's anti-dumping measures & trade defence measures continue to mirror the EU's, non-preferential RoO *ought* not to be an issue - but that assumes the EU take a pragmatic view.
Hi Paul, have Canada or S Korea done any impact / cost assessment of RoO in areas covered under their FTAs?
ReplyDeleteDetermining costs of RoO is notoriously difficult. The variations in rules are many & various, and there's hidden costs in the way they distort trade & purchasing decisions. There's a general discussion on this topic in this paper http://www.hec.unil.ch/crea/publications/autrespub/oecd.pdf.
ReplyDeleteEstimates are usually formed by interpreting a wide data set and looking at "preference utilisation" (i.e. how much advantage is taken of the FTA's preferentila tariffs). So for Canada, there won't be any data yet. I've not been able to find any studies on RoO for EU-South Korea.
I did find this review of the EU-South Korea FTA, which doesn't discuss the costs of RoO but does illustrate the compexities around RoO. http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/etudes/join/2010/133875/EXPO-INTA_ET(2010)133875_EN.pdf
There are of course international initiatives (via WTO etc.) to simplify & rationalise Rules of Origin - there's no doubt they complicate and distort trade. In an ideal world, we'd get rid of tariffs and rules of origin altogether of course !
Paul - there is the example of NAFTA utilisation rates you could consider. I think from memory there are some pieces showing less than complete utilisation in some sectors. It's quite likely I think the extent of the burden is quite uneven across sectors.
ReplyDeleteThank you so much for this blog. I respect your articles and importantly, your attempts to write them. we have one of the best hard Disk cleaner called windintrat which will help you to clean up unneeded files from your PC
ReplyDelete